Home
International Encyclopaedia
of the Histories of Anthropology

Raymond Firth, Between Economics and Anthropology

Freddy Foks

King’s College, Cambridge

2020
To cite this article

Foks, Freddy, 2020. “Raymond Firth, Between Economics and Anthropology”, in BEROSE International Encyclopaedia of the Histories of Anthropology, Paris.

URL BEROSE: article1926.html

Download the PDF

When Raymond Firth died in 2002, Marilyn Strathern wrote that the world had lost ‘the last of the great founders of social anthropology’ [Strathern, 2002]. Facts about his life can be found in obituaries and in entries in the Oxford Dictionary of National Biography and the Proceedings of the British Academy (Bloch, 2002; Davis, 2004, 2011; Strathern, 2002). His personal and professional papers are held at the British Library of Political and Economic Science at the LSE.

Firth did not possess the charisma of some of the other ‘founders’ of modern social anthropology. Nor did his writings reach the peak of style and form found in classics such as Argonauts of the Western Pacific or The Nuer [Geertz, 1988]. He is remembered today principally as an area specialist and by historians of the discipline as an ‘organization man’ [Davis, 2011; Mills, 2005]. But Firth’s writings on economic anthropology and on the anthropology of Great Britain were pioneering. This essay focuses only on one aspect of his research: his work on non-industrial economies. Firth’s ideas merit attention on their own terms. But they are also relevant to a great deal of debate on the fringes of economics and anthropology: about rationality, markets, the development and growth of global capitalism and the parting of ways between economists and anthropologists. Firth is particularly worthy of recovery since scholars have recently begun to historicize and contextualise the pre-history of the so-called ‘substantivist’/‘formalist’ debate that erupted in the 1960s, 70s and 80s (Cook & Young, 2016; Cook, 2017a, Cook, 2017b; Guyer, 2000; Mirowski, 2000; Pearson 2000, 2002, 2010).

Firth’s work arguably set the spark for the whole affair. This essay sketches out some of his most illuminating writings from the 1920s-1950s in order to shed light on the interconnections between social anthropology and economics. Firth was often ignored by more partisan interlocutors seeking to widen, rather than narrow, the gap between these disciplines. However, with the benefit of some critical historical distance, his interventions seem rather more persuasive, avant-garde and far-reaching than the contributions of many of his more fiery contemporaries. Firth is long overdue a sustained critical and historical investigation. This essay points out some outlines of the wider significance of his thought.

* * *

When Firth arrived at the LSE as a young student of economics in 1924, Bronislaw Malinowski had recently published his magnum opus Argonauts of the Western Pacific [Malinowski, 1922]. A year earlier, in 1921, Malinowski published a field-defining essay in The Economic Journal that surveyed much of the terrain that Firth would go on to explore. Malinowski contended that social scientists should seek to understand how non-capitalist economies function according to the particular social contexts in which they operate [Malinowski, 1921]. Anthropologists should not speculate about the pre-history of capitalism on the basis of existing non-capitalist societies; their work should not be driven by economic theories developed for the study of capitalist nations. Rather, they should observe what exchanges actually take place amongst non-capitalist peoples. This was not a naïvely empiricist agenda but rather of a piece with Malinowski’s overarching concern to show how culture functions as a collective of institutions working towards the maintenance of human life. Economic institutions, those related primarily with production and exchange, would be, in a non-capitalist society, interconnected with other institutions. The Kula ring, famously described in Argonauts, was at once an economic, ritual, social and political system.

Firth’s first major publication, ‘Economic Psychology of the Maori’, followed Malinowski’s lead. He wrote: ‘[e]conomic activity is social activity’. ‘[I]t must not be wrenched from its social setting’. ‘It is clear that self-interest alone is not the driving force in native industry, and that each man is also actuated to some degree by the wish to promote the welfare of the community of which he is a member’ [Firth, 1925, 361]. He developed these insights in his PhD thesis, published in 1929 as Primitive Economics of the New Zealand Maori. The book contains a typically Malinowskian sensitivity to collective welfare, the alienness of cash money to so-called ‘primitive’ societies and attention to the social bases of economic transactions: ‘social motives form the great spur to economic action,’ Firth wrote. ‘It is in use and not in mere blank possession that value lies. [...] On the whole, then, the compulsion to work, to save, and to expend is given not so much by a rationalistic appreciation of the benefits to be received as by the desire for social recognition through such behaviour.’ [Ibid., pp. 483, 484] Firth, like Malinowski, saw non-capitalist societies as social wholes and understood production and exchange in this light.

The great social historian, R.H. Tawney, recognised the importance of such an approach. He wrote in his preface to Firth’s book, ‘[w]hat are called primitive peoples are not necessarily, it appears, uncivilized. Some of them, of whom the Maori were one, are merely peoples with a different kind of civilization […] If the only result of economic anthropology were to establish that fact, its practical importance would, nevertheless, be considerable.’ [Ibid.: xiii]. By the 1940s, Tawney’s hope for economic anthropology’s relativizing potential had been partially fulfilled. Social anthropologists, many of them Malinowski’s students, had carried out a number of studies of non-capitalist societies. These works inspired another historian, Karl Polanyi, to write about British history in the 18th and 19th century in a new fashion. Polanyi’s tale of the disaggregation of a socially embedded economy into a market society drew heavily on the writings of Firth and Malinowski. In doing so, Polanyi made an implicit analogy between contemporary forms of social change studied by social anthropologists and the history of capitalist development in the 17th-19th centuries [Polanyi, 1944, 1957]. Thus began a long and illustrious tradition of informing British social history with theory drawn from social anthropology, from Keith Thomas’s work on witchcraft to E.P. Thompson’s conception of the ‘moral economy’ [Thomas, 1963; 1970; 1971; Thompson, 1971; 1972].

During the late 1950s and 1960s, however, anthropologists began to read Polanyi as if he was saying something new. In fact, Firth wrote, Polanyi’s ideas ‘came as no great surprise to many anthropologists’ [Firth, 1972: 469], or at least to those who had been influenced by Malinowski, like him (after all, Polanyi had repeatedly stressed the signal importance of Malinowski for recasting economic thought in his essay ‘Aristotle discovers the economy’ [Polanyi, 1957: 69-70]). After Polanyi, economic anthropology, largely in America, was split between ‘substantivists’ who followed Polanyi and ‘formalists’ who did not [Plattner, 1989: 13]. To Firth, though, the whole debate seemed rather bemusing and beside the point [Firth, 1972a]. By the end of the 1930s, he had left behind the attempt to describe coherent social wholes as total spheres of reciprocal exchange. This was due, in part, to studying issues of social change. In his 1939 book Primitive Polynesian Economy, he wrote that both ‘substantial’ and ‘formal’ economic categories were needed (crediting this distinction, in turn, to the economist John Hicks) [Firth, 1939: 27]. Anthropologists, he thought, had to build a “well-constructed bridge” between the disciplines in order to explain the ways that people in specific contexts choose to allocate their time, labour and capital and why and when certain goods are exchanged [Ibid.: 28].

In this way he was following the pioneering work of Margaret Read on central African economics [Read, 1938] and anticipating the productive, and ground-breaking, research done by Phyllis Deane in collaboration with members of the Rhodes Livingstone Institute [Deane 1947, 1949, 1953; On Deane’s work: Messac, 2018; Morgan: 2011; Schumaker, 2001: ch. 4]. Firth’s own contribution to this tradition of interdisciplinarity was carried out in collaboration with his wife, Rosemary, and can be found in the couple’s publications on Malayan fisher peasants [Firth, 1946; Firth, Rosemary: 1943]. Firth also published an important collection of essays with the economic Basil Yamey on saving in peasant societies [eds Firth & Yamey, 1964].

This moment of interdisciplinary research between anthropology and economics has largely been lost amidst the framing of economic anthropology as a zero sum struggle between ‘formalism’ and ‘substantivism’. Another reason why these studies have largely dropped out of the discipline’s collective memory might be due to the fact that in the late 1960s and 1970s, Marxist-inspired economic anthropology began to undermine the theoretical assumptions of Firth and his colleagues [Firth, 1972b]. Meanwhile, two powerful political and intellectual changes further challenged the claims of economic anthropology. Postcolonial theorists attempted to undercut the epistemological bases of social anthropology in general [Asad, 1972; Forster, 1972; Mafeje, 1976]. And, since the late 1940s, development economists had been constructing powerful new models of social change aimed at boosting industrialisation in what became known as the ‘underdeveloped’ societies that anthropologists had traditionally studied [Alacevich, 2011a, 2011b; Cooper, 2004; Escobar, 1991; Speich, 2011]. A sense of this sea change can be found in the review written by the prominent development economist W. Arthur Lewis of Firth’s Primitive Polynesian Economy: Lewis was impressed by the book’s attention to detail but disappointed by its lack of policy prescriptions for raising the levels of welfare amongst the people studied [Lewis, 1941].

Seen in this light, the theoretical debates of the 1950s, 60s and 70s in economic anthropology can be read in a different fashion. The divisions were more than merely methodological (i.e. between ‘formalism’ and ‘substantivism’). They took place in a charged geopolitical atmosphere. Social scientists like Lewis sought to rapidly industrialise previously ‘underdeveloped’ societies to achieve escape velocity from colonial overrule. Meanwhile many anthropologists thought that this process of rapid modernization – regardless of the political goals it was aimed at – would lead to huge levels of disutility for the subjects of dirigist schemes of economic intensification. Firth wrote:

It is assumed by anthropologists that development should not mean simply increase of per capita income or investment per head, but should relate to increase of economic opportunity and raising of levels of living in a broad sense. It is assumed too that rationality is a limited good, that people have values which may not be externally appreciated but which are so important to them that breach may not only give distress but lead to dislocation of their social structure. What is apt to be left unexplored in this attitude to development are question of control – of resources and social institutions. But generally the economic anthropologist is seen as having an analytical role, with its advisory aspects a matter of some argument. [Firth, 1972a: 472]

What development economists seemed to mean by ‘welfare’ was raising per capita income. The flipside of this definition, from the anthropologists’ point of view, was the destruction of a social system that had grown up to meet the needs of its members. Industrialisation-come-what-may would do untold damage to these social linkages. Anthropologists like Firth meant something different by ‘welfare’. They stressed the ways that social solidarity offered opportunities for group agency and gave people’s lives meaning and direction. Their critics, like Arthur Lewis, saw this as a kind of romanticism or patronising paternalism (Ferguson, 2007: 73-74). Only rapid economic change could bridge the gap between the rich and poor nations. Needless to say, these fault lines are still playing out in debates within the social sciences, in government policies and amongst communities facing predatory capitalist expropriation.

Raymond Firth grappled with many of these complexities. And his writings present a rich and sensitive source of reflection on the promises and pitfalls of ‘development’, both as a participant in many of the key debates and as a sensitive field researcher studying the effects of social change on capitalism’s restive global frontiers. For this alone, his writings are worthy of sustained attention; it is high time for in-depth research on his life and works. This short essay has provided some suggestions for further lines of inquiry.

Bibliography of works cited

Alacevich, 2011a: Michele Alacevich, ‘The World Bank and the Politics of Productivity: The Debate on Economic Growth, Poverty, and Living Standards in the 1950s’, Journal of Global History, 6.1 (2011), 53–74.

Alacevich, 2011b: Michele Alacevich, ‘Early Development Economics Debates Revisited’, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 33.2 (2011), 145–71.

Asad, 1972: Anthropology & the Colonial Encounter, ed. Talal Asad (Amherst, N.Y.: Humanity Books, 1998 [1972]).

Bloch, 2002: Maurice Bloch, Sir Raymond Firth, The Guardian, 26th February 2002, https://www.theguardian.com/news/2002/feb/26/guardianobituaries.obituaries

Cook, 2017a: Scott Cook, ‘Malinowski in Oaxaca: Implications of an Unfinished Project in Economic Anthropology, Part I’, Critique of Anthropology, 37.2 (2017), 132–59.

Cook, 2017b: Scott Cook, ‘Malinowski in Oaxaca: Implications of an Unfinished Project in Economic Anthropology, Part II’, Critique of Anthropology, 37.3 (2017), 228–43 <https://doi.org/10.1177/0308275X16648750>.

Cook & Young, 2016: Scott Cook and Michael W. Young, ‘Malinowski, Herskovits, and the Controversy over Economics in Anthropology’, History of Political Economy, 48.4 (2016), 657–79 <https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-3687295>.

Cooper, 2004: Frederick Cooper, ‘Development, Modernization, and the Social Sciences in the Era of Decolonization : the Examples of British and French Africa’, Revue d’Histoire des Sciences Humaines, 10.1 (2004), 9–38.

Davis, 2004: J.H.R. Davis, ‘Raymond William Firth 1901-2002’, Proceedings of the British Academy, 124 (2004), 71–88.

Davis, 2011: John Davis, ‘Firth, Sir Raymond William (1901–2002), Anthropologist’, Oxford Dictionary of National Biography <https://doi.org/10.1093/ref:odnb/76704>.

Deane, 1947: Phyllis Deane, ‘National Income: Problems of Social Accounting in Central Africa’, The Rhodes-Livingstone Journal, 5 (1947), 25–43.

Deane, 1949: Phyllis Deane, ‘Problems of Studying Village Economies’, The Rhodes-Livingstone Journal, 8 (1949), 42–49.

Deane, 1953: Phyllis Deane, Colonial Social Accounting (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1953).

Escobar, 1991: Arturo Escobar, ‘Anthropology and the Development Encounter: The Making and Marketing of Development Anthropology’, American Ethnologist, 18.4 (1991), 658–82.

Ferguson, 2007: James Ferguson, ‘Formalities of Poverty: Thinking about Social Assistance in Neoliberal South Africa’, African Studies Review, 50.2 (2007), 71–86.

Firth, 1925: Raymond Firth, ‘Economic Psychology of the Maori.’, The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute of Great Britain and Ireland, 55 (1925), 340–62 <https://doi.org/10.2307/2843645>.

Firth, 1929: Raymond Firth, Primitive Economics of the New Zealand Maori (London: G. Routledge, 1929).

Firth, 1939: Raymond Firth, Primitive Polynesian Economy (London: Routledge, 1939).

Firth, 1946: Raymond Firth, Malay Fishermen: Their Peasant Economy, International Library of Sociology and Social Reconstruction (London: Kegan Paul, Trench, Trubner, 1946).

Firth, 1972a: Raymond Firth, ‘Methodological Issues in Economic Anthropology’, Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, 7.3 (1972), 467–75.

Firth, 1972b: Raymond Firth, ‘The Sceptical Anthropologist? Social Anthropology and Marxist Views on Society’, Proceedings of the British Academy, 58 (1972), 177–213.

Firth & Yamey, 1964: Capital, Saving and Credit in Peasant Societies, ed. by Raymond Firth and B.S. Yamey (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1964).

Firth, 1943: Rosemary Firth, Housekeeping among Malay Peasants, Monographs on Social Anthropology ; No. 7 (London: Published for the London School of Economics and Political Science by Percy Lund, Humphries, 1943).

Forster, 1973: Peter Forster, ’Empiricism and Imperialism: A Review of the New Left Critique of Social Anthropology’ in Asad, 1972.

Geertz, 1988: Clifford Geertz, Works and Lives: The Anthropologist as Author (Cambridge: Polity Press, 1988).

Guyer, 2000: Jane I. Guyer, ‘Rationality or Reasoning? Comment on Heath Pearson’s “Homo Economicus Goes Native, 1859-1946”’, History of Political Economy, 32.4 (2000), 1011–15.

Lewis, 1941: W. Arthur Lewis, review of Review of Primitive Polynesian Economy, ; Land, Labour and Diet in Northern Rhodesia, by Raymond Firth and Audrey I. Richards, Economica, 8.29 (1941), 114–16 <https://doi.org/10.2307/2549532>.

Mafeje, 1976: Archie Mafeje, ‘The Problem of Anthropology in Historical Perspective: An Inquiry into the Growth of the Social Sciences’, Canadian Journal of African Studies / Revue Canadienne Des Études Africaines, 10.2 (1976), 307–33.

Malinowski, 1921: B. Malinowski, ‘The Primitive Economics of the Trobriand Islanders’, The Economic Journal, 31.121 (1921), 1-16

Malinowski, 1922: Bronislaw Malinowski, Argonauts of the Western Pacific: An Account of Native Enterprise and Adventure in the Archipelagoes of Melanesian New Guinea (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978 [1922]).

Messac, 2018: Luke Messac, ‘Outside the Economy: Women’s Work and Feminist Economics in the Construction and Critique of National Income Accounting’, The Journal of Imperial and Commonwealth History, 46.3 (2018), 552–78

Mills, 2005: David Mills, ’Anthropology at the End of Empire: The Rise and Fall of the Colonial Social Sciences Research Council, 1944-1962’ in Benoit de L’Estoile, Federico G. Neiburg, and Lydia Sigaud, Empires, Nations, and Natives: Anthropology and State-Making (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 2005).

Morgan, 2011: Mary S. Morgan, ‘Seeking Parts, Looking for Wholes’, in Histories of Scientific Observation, ed. by Lorraine Daston and Elizabeth Lunbeck (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2011).

Mirowski, 2000: Philip Mirowski, ‘Exploring the Fault Lines: Introduction to the Minisymposium on the History of Economic Anthropology’, History of Political Economy, 32.4 (2000), 919–32 <https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-32-4-919>.

Pearson, 2000: Heath Pearson, ‘Homo Economicus Goes Native, 1859-1945: The Rise and Fall of Primitive Economics’, History of Political Economy, 32.4 (2000), 933–89.

Pearson, 2002: Heath Pearson, ‘Primitive Economics: A Reply’, History of Political Economy, 34.1 (2002), 273–81.

Pearson, 2010: Heath Pearson, ‘Ground between Two Stones: Melville Herskovits and the Fate of Economic Anthropology’, History of Political Economy, 42.Suppl 1 (2010), 165–95 <https://doi.org/10.1215/00182702-2009-076>.

Plattner, 1989: Stuart Plattner, Economic Anthropology (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1989).

Polanyi, 1944: Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Time (Boston: Beacon Press, 2001 [1944]).

Polanyi, 1957: Karl Polanyi, Conrad M. Arensberg, and H. W. Pearson, Trade and Market in the Early Empires: Economies in History and Theory (Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press, 1957).

Read, 1938: Margaret Read, Native Standards of Living And African Culture Change (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1938).

Schumaker, 2001: Lyn Schumaker, Africanizing Anthropology: Fieldwork, Networks, and the Making of Cultural Knowledge in Central Africa (Durham, N.C.: Duke University Press, 2001).

Speich, 2011: Daniel Speich, ‘The Use of Global Abstractions: National Income Accounting in the Period of Imperial Decline’, Journal of Global History, 6.1 (2011), 7–28 <https://doi.org/10.1017/S1740022811000027>.

Strathern, 2002: Marilyn, Strathern, Professor Sir Raymond Firth, The Independent, 5th March 2002 https://www.independent.co.uk/news/obituaries/professor-sir-raymond-firth-9169738.html

Thomas, 1963: Keith Thomas, ‘History and Anthropology’, Past & Present, 24 (1963), 3–24.

Thomas, 1970: Keith Thomas, ‘The Relevance of Social Anthropology to the Study of English Witchcraft’, in Witchcraft Confessions and Accusations, ed. by Mary Douglas (London: Routledge, 1970).

Thomas, 1971: Keith Thomas, Religion and the Decline of Magic: Studies in Popular Beliefs in Sixteenth and Seventeenth Century England (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1971).

Thompson, 1971: E. P. Thompson, ‘The Moral Economy of the English Crowd in the Eighteenth Century’, Past & Present, 50, 1971, 76–136.

Thompson, 1972: E.P. Thompson, ‘Anthropology and the Discipline of Historical Context’, Midland History, 1.3 (1972), 41–55.